Fact-checking drought-water pricing

Fact-checking drought-water pricing

 

This is Part 2 of a series. Part 1 was on how drought-water pricing violates Proposition 218’s ban on tax increases without a vote of the people. Drought, Sept. 16, 2014

What is good water pricing during a drought? Let’s look at some situations.

1. Voluntary conservation

A good place to start is the continuing series on the drought by Caitrin Chappelle and Ellen Hanak of the Public Policy Institute of California. It their Sept. 3 installment, they tout the city of Roseville as an example of good drought pricing:

“The city of Roseville is one community using the drought pricing tool, which was adopted — and vetted with customers — before the drought hit. In June, Roseville implemented a temporary 15 percent drought surcharge while also mandating a 20 percent reduction in water use.”

But here’s how Roseville itself justified increasing water rates:

“With almost three months of declining revenue and increased costs, the water utilities financial reserves are no longer able to cover this deficit. Costs are increasing for many reasons — water is scarcer and more expensive. The drought has also required us to expand our water conservation programs, invest in operation of our back-up groundwater wells, and build new wells as water from Folsom Lake has become much less reliable due to an unprecedented drought.”

In other words, customers were curtailing water use voluntarily at the onset of the drought and water utility revenues dropped below fixed costs. Customers (“the market”) had already reacted by cutting water use.

But public utilities are not allowed to run an operating deficit.  Thus, Roseville appropriately raised water rates to cover their fixed costs, and for drilling new wells, without needing to get voter approval under Prop. 218. So Roseville’s water rate increase did not use a “drought pricing tool” to spur conservation, because conservation already was happening.

2. Agricultural pricing

Many agricultural water districts have been hit hard. Shouldn’t they impose a “conservation rate”?

Actually, water sales by auctions already adjust for the scarcity of water due to drought. So there is no need to impose water conservation rates on farmers.

During wet years, water auction prices commonly range in the hundreds of dollars per acre-foot. But during droughts, that typically increases at least tenfold to the range of thousands of dollars per acre-foot.

Once again, the market itself has imposed “conservation water rates.”

3. Senior water-rights farmers

Some farmers have “senior water rights” and are entitled to deliveries of cheap system water through the State Water Project. Are they overusing water because it is so cheap at the expense of everyone else?  No.

Like electricity, farming water commonly is not bid on each day or month on the spot market. Instead, contracts are for years, even decades, because of the large capital investment needed upfront for land, seeds and farming equipment. Such water contracts are a market mechanism to ensure continued supply at affordable prices.

Hanak mentions in her “California Water Markets by the Number – Update 2012” that water markets have evolved from one year contracts to longer-term contracts and trades.  The number of short-term contracts increases during droughts (see Figure 3, Page 19 here).

So those with locked-in lower water rates by contract in a drought aren’t getting away with anything. If the government violated these contracts to take the water, or force the farmers to pay higher rates, it would be a “taking,” which the U.S. Supreme Court has ruled must be compensated. That would mean taxpayers would pick up the tab. The court affirmed its previous rulings last year in Koontz vs. St. Johns River Water Management District.

Moreover, the water contract market is highly developed.

4. Selling wholesale water to farmers

The UC Davis Center for Watershed Sciences proposes selling government wholesale water allocated to fish and wildlife refuges back to farmers at duress drought water prices. But that’s fraught with double-payment problems because farmers have already paid for the water once to maintain California’s Central Valley Project.

Such sales would not reflect fair market pricing and are probably illegal under the eminent domain “project influence rule.” That rule says you can’t take water from farmers for a public project to protect fish, create an artificial scarcity, then charge farmers the higher scarcity price in a drought.

5. Supply-side solutions

The above solutions are “demand-side solutions” to drought: they reduce the use of water.

But what about “supply-side solutions,” that increase the supply of water? As reported earlier on CalWatchdog.com, such solutions are being pursued by the city of San Antonio, Tex., and by Cadiz, Inc. in California.

The big benefit of supply-side solutions is that they don’t take water from one use and give it to another. Rather, they develop water for new uses, reducing legal and regulatory entanglements.

Conclusion

Drought-water pricing advocates largely are experts in academia and think tanks. Yet the reality in the pipes, so to speak, is what goes on in the water contract market and with established law.

Our system of government requires the rule of law and the consent of the governed, which is missing in calls to increase water rates to curtail usage of water.


 

Wayne Lusvardi worked for 20 years for one of California’s largest water agencies as Chief Real Estate Appraiser in the valuation, leasing and management of land with water rights, including the Palo Verde Irrigation District land fallowing program.

3 comments

Write a comment
  1. LetitCollapse
    LetitCollapse 22 September, 2014, 15:21

    Water will become the new oil if we have another winter drought. Whenever we fall below average rainfall the solution is always to raise the water rates. Yet I recall when we had 30″ of rain one winter. We were swimming in water. We had so much water we didn’t know what to do with it all. Did the water rates drop? Not a single penny. Supply and demand doesn’t even enter into the equation unless there’s a drought and an alleged shortage. Then the law of economics raises it’s ugly head. Otherwise it’s ignored.

    The ruling class will use any crisis to their own advantage. If there’s an opportunity to dig deeper into your wallet, they’ll find a way. They got ya by the short hairs.

    Reply this comment
  2. eff it!
    eff it! 23 September, 2014, 13:15

    Anybody who graduated a 6th grade math class can tell you the world has never had any more, or any less water. In Commiefornia we suffer from a lack of infrustructure and the capacity to hold on to the water (wells/ resevoirs). Yet in a state where the average annual budget approaches 100 billion, our legislators can’t find a measly 7% (7 billion) of that to trim just once to fix the problem. Instead, the voters will be asked to borrow that money, so that we can fix the problem, while spending 11 billion for the repairs…We’re screwed!!!

    Reply this comment
  3. DJ
    DJ 25 September, 2014, 12:55

    Thanks to the author for providing a well-organized, well-argued post with links to all of the sources!

    I’m a little unclear still, though, what your solutions are that would not require any incurred costs and also limit withdrawals to prevent literally running out of water (eff it, even if the water supply quantity has stayed the same, there are more people using more water… increased storage capacity ain’t gonna cut it in watersheds that are >200% overutilized). So, regarding solutions, a few quick points:

    – Supply side increases? What if the technology is not currently economically feasible? Do you subsidize it with… increased taxes? Most supply increases are currently far more economically unfeasible than other proposed solutions.

    – Clearly the current permitting/auctioning/rights methods aren’t working. Yeah, it sucks if someone has bought and paid for water withdrawal rights and it gets taken away, but it also sucks when water supplies for a watershed or region hit zero and NOBODY can use it. This is a collective problem and if each person says “I paid for it 1/5/10 years ago, I deserve to get what I paid for,” everyone is going to be SOL really soon.

    Reply this comment

Write a Comment

<



Related Articles

Trouble at Developmental Services

AUGUST 25, 2010 By ANTHONY PIGNATARO This should sound familiar to many people. “(T)here is not really any communication between

High-Speed Rail Crashes Into Legislature

APRIL 27, 2011 By KATY GRIMES The costs and the legislation for the California High-Speed Rail Authority keep speeding toward

Falling gas revenue sharpens CA infrastructure fight

As revenues from the statewide gasoline tax tanked amid low prices, lawmakers in Sacramento faced a fiercer debate over how